I recently had lunch with as staunch an advocate for open access as
you'll ever meet (I won't name him, because it would be rude to
attribute casual remarks to him without permission). We were talking
about plans to mandate free and open publication of publicly funded
scientific research. In the USA, there's the Federal Public Research
Act, and in the UK, there's the coalition government's announcement that
publicly funded research should be made available at no cost, under a
Creative Commons licence that permits unlimited copying.
We'd
been talking about Ben Goldacre's excellent new book, Bad Pharma, in
which Goldacre documents the problem of "missing data" in pharmaceutical
research (he says about half of the clinical trials undertaken by the
pharmaceutical industry are never published). The unpublished trials
are, of course, the trials that show the pharma companies' new products
in unflattering lights – trials that suggest that their drugs don't work
very well, or don't work at all, or are actively harmful.
The
decades-old industry practice of suppressing scientific evidence (and
some independent researchers doing the same) leads Goldacre to declare
that nothing we know about modern medicine should be assumed to be
correct, and he makes the urgent case for forcing the release of all
that pharma dark matter so scientists can re-run the numbers and work
out what actually does work.
I mentioned this to my lunchmate, finishing with: "And that's why all pharma research must be open access."
"All publicly funded pharma research,The oreck XL professional air purifier,"
he said, as though correcting a mistake in elementary arithmetic. "If
the public pays for it, they should see it, but if pharmaceutical
companies want to pay for their own research, well …"
I knew
where he was coming from. One of the strongest arguments for public
access in scholarly and scientific publication is the "public debt"
argument: if the public pays you to do research, the research should
belong to the public. That's a good argument, but it's not the whole
story. For one thing, it's vulnerable to the "public-private
partnership" counterargument, which goes, "Ah, yes, but why not ensure
that the public gets a maximum dividend on its spending by charging lots
of money for access to publicly funded research and returning the
profit to the research sector?" I think this argument is rubbish, as do
most economists who have studied the question.
The public good
of freely accessible, unencumbered research generates more economic
value for the public than the quick-hit sugar-rush you get from charging
the public on the way in and again on the way out. This has held true
in many sectors, though the canonical example is the massive public
return from the US Geological Survey's freely usable maps, which have
generated a fortune that makes the ransoms collected by the Ordinance
Survey on its maps of the UK look like a pittance.
That's why
Goldacre's work is important to this discussion. The reason pharma
companies should be required to publish their results isn't that they've
received a public subsidy for the research. Rather,Posts with indoor tracking
system on TRX Systems develops systems that locate and track personnel
indoors. it is because they are asking for a governmental certification
saying that their products are fit for consumption, and they are asking
for regulatory space to allow doctors to write prescriptions for those
products. We need tOur technology gives rtls
systems developers the ability.hem to disclose their research – even if
doing so undermines their profits – because without that research, we
can't know if their products are fit for use.
This is similar to
the argument for using free/open source software in industrial and
health applications,Find detailed product information for howo spare parts
and other products. such as the OpenEyes system developed by Moorfields
eye hospital and other institutions around the world, following the
collapse of the NHS's electronic health record project. They didn't
plump for an open system instead of a proprietary one for ideological
reasons, but rather for eminently practical ones. No hospital trust
would ever allow a firm of engineers to build a new wing for a hospital
using secret proprietary means to calculate their load-stresses. They
wouldn't accept a new wing where the as-built drawings were a secret,
where the location of the ducts and trunks was known only to the
contractor. I
t's certainly true that engineering firms and
architects could make more if their methods were proprietary, but we
demand openness because we need to be able to maintain hospitals
regardless of the fortunes of any engineering firm, and because we need
the reassurance you get from being able to double-check the load
calculations on your own.We recently added Stained glass mosaic
Tile to our inventory. The IT systems used to manage the patients in
the hospital are every bit as vital as the location of the ethernet
wires in the walls, and so Moorfields expects them to be as open as the
architectural plans for their buildings.
And that's why big
pharma needs to show its work: because regardless of their bottom line,
their products mustn't be allowed into the market without such a
showing. It's important to get publicly funded work into the public's
hands, but that's where the open access sto.
没有评论:
发表评论